HANDY is creating a big business out of small jobs. The company finds
its customers self-employed home-helps available in the right place and
at the right time. All the householder needs is a credit card and a
phone equipped with Handy’s app, and everything from spring cleaning to
flat-pack-furniture assembly gets taken care of by “service pros” who
earn an average of $18 an hour. The company, which provides its service
in 29 of the biggest cities in the United States, as well as Toronto,
Vancouver and six British cities, now has 5,000 workers on its books; it
says most choose to work between five hours and 35 hours a week, and
that the 20% doing most earn $2,500 a month. The company has 200
full-time employees. Founded in 2011, it has raised $40m in venture
capital.
Handy is one of a large number of startups built around systems which
match jobs with independent contractors on the fly, and thus supply
labour and services on demand. In San Francisco—which is, with New York,
Handy’s hometown, ground zero for this on-demand economy—young
professionals who work for Google and Facebook can use the apps on their
phones to get their apartments cleaned by Handy or Homejoy; their
groceries bought and delivered by Instacart; their clothes washed by
Washio and their flowers delivered by BloomThat. Fancy Hands will
provide them with personal assistants who can book trips or negotiate
with the cable company. TaskRabbit will send somebody out to pick up a
last-minute gift and Shyp will gift-wrap and deliver it. SpoonRocket
will deliver a restaurant-quality meal to the door within ten minutes.
The obvious inspiration for all this is Uber, a car service which was
founded in San Francisco in 2009 and which already operates in 53
countries; insiders say it will have sales of more than $1 billion in
2014. SherpaVentures, a venture-capital company, calculates that Uber
and two other car services, Lyft and Sidecar, made $140m in revenues in
San Francisco in 2013, half what the established taxi companies took
(see chart 1), and the company shows every sign of doing the same
wherever local regulators give it room. Its latest funding round valued
it at $40 billion. Even in a frothy market, that is a remarkable figure.
Bashing Uber has become an industry in its own right; in some
circles, though, applying its business model to any other service
imaginable is even more popular. There seems to be a near-endless
succession of bright young people promising venture capitalists that
they can be “the Uber of X”, where X is anything one of those bright
young people can imagine wanting done for them (see chart 2). They have
created a plethora of on-demand companies that put time-starved urban
professionals in timely contact with job-starved workers, creating a
sometimes distasteful caricature of technology-driven social disparity
in the process; an article about the on-demand economy by Kevin Roose in
New York magazine began with the revelation that the housecleaner he hired through Homejoy lived in a homeless shelter.
This boom marks a striking new stage in a deeper transformation.
Using the now ubiquitous platform of the smartphone to deliver labour
and services in a variety of new ways will challenge many of the
fundamental assumptions of 20th-century capitalism, from the nature of
the firm to the structure of careers.
The young Turks
The new opportunities that technology offers for matching jobs to
workers were being exploited well before Uber. Topcoder was founded in
2001 to give programmers a venue to show off. In 2013, it was bought by
Appirio, a cloud-services company, and now specialises in providing the
services of freelance coders. Elance-oDesk offers 4m companies the
services of 10m freelances. The model is also gaining ground in the
professions. Eden McCallum, which was founded in London in 2000, can tap
into a network of 500 freelance consultants in order to offer
consulting services at a fraction of the cost of big consultancies like
McKinsey. This allows it to provide consulting to small companies as
well as to concerns like GSK, a pharma giant. Axiom employs 650 lawyers,
services half the
Fortune 100 companies, and
enjoyed revenues of more than $100m in 2012. Medicast is applying a
similar model to doctors in Miami, Los Angeles and San Diego. Patients
order a doctor by touching an app (which also registers where they are).
A doctor briefed on the symptoms is guaranteed to arrive within two
hours; the basic cost is $200 a visit. Not least because it provides
malpractice insurance, the company is particularly attractive to
moonlighters who want to top up their income, younger doctors without
the capital to start their own practices and older doctors who want to
set their own timetables.
The Los Angeles-based Business Talent Group provides bosses on tap
for companies that want to tackle a specific problem without adding
another senior executive to the payroll: Fox Mobile Entertainment, an
online-content provider, turned to it for a temporary creative director
to produce a new line of products. Creative companies add a twist to the
model: they demand ideas, rather than labour and services, and give a
prize or prizes only to the ones they find interesting. Innocentive has
applied the prize idea to corporate R&D; it turns companies’
research needs into specific problems and pays for satisfactory
solutions to them.
A job for the afternoon
Tongal does the same thing with its network of 40,000 video-makers.
In 2012 Colgate-Palmolive, a consumer-goods company, offered $17,000 to
anyone who could make a 30-second advertisement for the internet. The ad
was so good that the company showed it at the Super Bowl alongside
blockbuster ads that cost hundreds of times more. Members of the Quirky
network post their product ideas on the company’s website. Other members
vote on the attractiveness of each idea and come up with ways of
turning it into reality. Since its birth in 2009 the company has
acquired over a million members and brought 400 products to the shops.
Perhaps the most striking of all the on-demand services is Amazon’s
Mechanical Turk, which allows customers to post any “human intelligence
task”, from flagging objectionable content on websites to composing text
messages; workers on the site choose what to do according to task and
price. The set-up uses to the full most of the capabilities and
advantages that make on-demand business models attractive: no need for
offices; no full-time contract employees; the clever use of computers to
repackage one set of people’s needs into another set of people’s tasks;
and an ability to access spare time and spare cognitive capacity all
across the world.
The idea that having a good job means being an employee of a
particular company is a legacy of a period that stretched from about
1880 to 1980. The huge companies created by the Industrial Revolution
brought armies of workers together, often under a single roof. In its
early stages this was a step down for many independent artisans who
could no longer compete with machine-made goods; it was a step up for
day-labourers who had survived by selling their labour to gang masters.
These companies introduced a new stability into work, a structure
which differentiated jobs from one another more clearly than before,
thus providing defined roles and new paths of career progress. Many of
the jobs were unionised, and the unions fought to improve their members’
benefits. Governments eventually built stable employment along these
lines into the heart of welfare legislation. A huge class of
white-collar workers enjoyed secure jobs administering the new economy.
For a while after the second world war everybody seemed to benefit
from this model: workers got security, benefits and steady wage rises;
companies got a stable workforce in which they could invest with a fair
expectation of returns. But the model started to get into trouble in the
1970s, thanks first to deteriorating industrial relations and then to
globalisation and computerisation. Trade unions have lost power in the
private sector, particularly in America and Britain, where legislation
has reduced their ability to take action (see chart 3). Companies kept
stricter control of their labour costs, increasingly contracting out
production in industrial businesses and re-engineering
middle-management. Computerisation and improved communications then sped
the process up, making it easier for companies to export jobs abroad,
to reshape them so that they could be done by less skilled contract
workers, or to eliminate them entirely.
This has all resulted in a more rootless and flexible labour force.
Pensioners and parents wanting or needing to spend more time on child
care swell the ranks of students and the straightforwardly unemployed. A
recent study by the Freelancers Union, a pressure group for freelance
workers, suggests that one in three members of the American workforce
(and a higher proportion of younger people) do some freelance work.
The on-demand economy is the result of pairing that workforce with
the smartphone, which now provides far more computing power than the
desktop computers which reshaped companies in the 1990s, and to far more
people (see chart 4 on next page). According to Benedict Evans of
Andreessen Horowitz, the new iPhones sold over the weekend of their
release in September 2014 contained 25 times more computing power than
the whole world had at its disposal in 1995. Connected to each other and
to yet more data and processing power in the cloud, these devices are
letting people design or find ad hoc answers to all sorts of business
problems previously solved by the structure of the firm.
Coase and effect
The way economists understand firms is largely based on an insight of
the late Ronald Coase. Firms make sense when the cost of organising
things internally through hierarchies is less than the cost of buying
things from the market; they are a way of dealing with the high
transaction costs faced when you need to do something moderately
complicated. Now that most people carry computers in their pockets which
can keep them connected with each other, know where they are,
understand their social network and so on, the transaction costs
involved in finding people to do things can be pushed a long way down.
This has a range of knock-on consequences, all of which are becoming
key features of the on-demand economy. One is further division of
labour. Thomas Malone, of the MIT Sloan School of Management, argues
that computer technology is producing an age of hyper-specialisation, as
the process that Adam Smith observed in a pin factory in the 1760s is
applied to more sophisticated jobs.
Another is the ability to tap underused capacity. This applies not
just to people’s time, but also to their assets: to drive for Lyft or
Uber, you do need a car. The on-demand economy is in many ways a
continuation of what has been called the “sharing economy” exemplified
by Airbnb, a company which turns apartments into guesthouses and their
owners into hoteliers. For people with few assets, though, on-demand
labour markets matter more.
And new areas are being opened to economies of scale. SpoonRocket
prepares its food in two central kitchens in San Francisco and Berkeley.
It delivers food quickly because it keeps a fleet of cars, equipped
with thermal bags to keep the food warm, roaming the streets of San
Francisco. “We’re like a gigantic cafeteria serving all of San
Francisco,” says Anson Tsui, one of the company’s founders.
Scheduling success
The aim of the on-demand companies is to exploit low transaction
costs in a number of ways. One key is providing the sort of trust that
encourages people to take a punt on the unfamiliar. Customers worry
about the quality of their temporary employees: nobody wants to give the
key to their apartment to a potential burglar, or their health details
to a dud doctor. Potential freelances, for their part, do not want to
have to deal with deadbeats: about 40% of freelances are currently paid
late.
On-demand companies like Handy provide customers with a guarantee
that workers are competent and honest; Oisin Hanrahan, the company’s
founder, says that more than 400,000 people have applied to join the
platform, but only 3% of applicants get through its selection and
vetting process. The workers, for their part, can hope for a steady flow
of jobs and prompt payment with minimal fuss. Handy’s computer system
also tries to schedule each worker’s jobs in such a way as to minimise
travel time.
Despite these capabilities, Handy is not necessarily looking at huge
success, any more than the other Ubers-of-X are. There are three reasons
for scepticism about their chances.
The first is that on-demand companies trying to keep the costs to
their clients as low as possible have difficulties training, managing
and motivating workers. MyClean, a cleaning service based in New York
City, tried using purely contract workers, but discovered that it got
better customer ratings if it used permanent staff. The company thinks
that better services justify higher labour costs. Uber drivers complain
that the company pays them like contract workers while seeking to manage
them like regular employees: they are told to take regular rather than
premium fares, but are not reimbursed for their fuel. America’s
gathering economic recovery may make it harder for companies to attract
casual labour as easily as they have done in the past few years.
The second problem is that on-demand companies seem likely to be
plagued by regulatory and political problems if they get large enough
for people to notice them. American on-demand companies are terrified
that they will be stuck with retrospective labour bills if the courts
force them to reclassify their workers as regular employees rather than
contract workers (a classification which is not always consistent from
jurisdiction to jurisdiction, raising the level of anxiety). Handy at
one point included a clause in its contracts imposing any such
retrospective costs on its clients, though it has now withdrawn it.
Faced by the threat of Uber, established taxi companies around the
world have organised strikes, filed lawsuits and leant on regulators. In
the Netherlands Uber has been banned; South Korea is treating it as an
illegal taxi service. In Germany anti-Uber feeling has nurtured a
broader criticism of “Plattform-Kapitalismus”; its perceived readiness
to reduce all aspects of people’s lives, from spare rooms to spare time,
to assets to be auctioned off is seen as deeply dehumanising. But such
protests often act as advertising for the services they are aimed
against. And a recent study revealed that American politicos spend more
on Uber than on regular taxis when campaigning, a strong indication that
the road ahead is likely to remain clear.
The third issue is size. The on-demand model obviously has network
effects: the home-help company with the most help on the books has the
best chance of providing a handyman at 10:30 sharp. Yet scaling up may
be difficult when barriers to entry are low and bonds of loyalty are
non-existent. It will be hard to get workers to be loyal to just one
middleman. A number of Uber drivers also work for Lyft.
In many service industries it is hard to see obvious economies of
scale on a national or global level. Being the best dry-cleaning service
in Cleveland does not necessarily offer a killer edge in Cologne. And
taste can be fickle, especially with companies that often look like
positional goods that trade, at least in part, on the cachet that they
confer to their consumers. Many of the people who currently regard
SpoonRocket as cool may drop it if it becomes a national brand.
On-demand companies may find themselves stuck in a world of low margins,
high promotional costs and labour churn as they struggle to attain the
sort of market dominance that locks in their network advantages. Alfred,
a subscription service, is already aggregating the work of specific
on-demand companies such as Instacart and Handy to offer its Boston
members a one-stop shop; such aggregation could drive down prices for
the basic on-demand providers yet further.
Everyone a corporation
Even if the eventual on-demand victors do carve out profitable
domestic-service businesses, many observers doubt that their model is
more broadly applicable. Some critics argue that on-demand companies
like BloomThat and Handy may be capable of delivering flowers or
cleaning houses, but when it comes to companies in the main flow of the
knowledge economy they are destined to remain marginal. This objection,
though, is not very convincing. The sort of people currently using Uber
are subject to the same forces as the people who drive them from place
to place.
The knowledge economy is subject to the same forces as the industrial
and service economies: routinisation, division of labour and
contracting out. A striking proportion of professional knowledge can be
turned into routine action, and the division of labour can bring big
efficiencies to the knowledge economy. Topcoder can undercut its rivals
by 75% by chopping projects into bite-sized chunks and offering them to
its 300,000 freelance developers in 200 countries as a series of
competitive challenges. Knowledge-intensive companies are already
contracting out more work to the market, partly to save costs and partly
to free up their cleverest workers to focus on the things that add the
most value. In 2008 Pfizer, a pharma company, undertook a huge
self-examination under the heading PfizerWorks. It realised that its
most highly skilled workers were spending 20% to 40% of their time on
routine work—entering data, producing PowerPoint slides, doing research
on the web. The company now contracts out much of this work.
Thus more and more of the routine parts of knowledge work can be
parcelled out to individuals, just as they were previously parcelled out
to companies. This could be bad news for the business models of
professional-service companies which use juniors to do fairly routine
work—thus providing the firm with income and the juniors with
training—while the partners do the more sophisticated stuff. As
on-demand solutions and automation prove applicable to more and more
routine work, that model becomes hard to sustain. InCloudCounsel
undercuts big law firms by as much as 80% thanks to an army of
freelances that processes legal documents (such as licences,
accreditation and non-disclosure agreements) for a flat fee.
The key role that cutting things up into routines plays in both
spheres suggests that the interaction between the on-demand economy and
automation will be a complex one. Gobbetising jobs with the aim of
parcelling them out to people who don’t see or need to see the big
picture is not that different from gobbetising them in a way that allows
automation. Often the first activity may prove a prelude to the second;
it is easy to see Uber as a forerunner to an eventual system that has
no drivers at all. In other cases, though, the cost-efficiency of
contracting out may reduce the incentives to automate.
What sort of world will this on-demand model create? Pessimists worry
that everyone will be reduced to the status of 19th-century dockers
crowded on the quayside at dawn waiting to be hired by a contractor.
Boosters maintain that it will usher in a world where everybody can
control their own lives, doing the work they want when they want it.
Both camps need to remember that the on-demand economy is not
introducing the serpent of casual labour into the garden of full
employment: it is exploiting an already casualised workforce in ways
that will ameliorate some problems even as they aggravate others.
The on-demand economy is unlikely to be a happy experience for people
who value stability more than flexibility: middle-aged professionals
with children to educate and mortgages to pay. On the other hand it is
likely to benefit people who value flexibility more than security:
students who want to supplement their incomes; bohemians who can afford
to dip in and out of the labour market; young mothers who want to
combine bringing up children with part-time jobs; the semi-retired,
whether voluntarily so or not.
Megan Guse, a law graduate, says that the on-demand model allows her
to combine a career as a lawyer with her taste for travel. “A lot of my
friends that have gone the Big Law route have these stories about having
to cancel weddings, vacations and miss family events. I can continue
working while being in exotic places.” Flexibility is also valuable for
elite workers who want to wind down after decades of selling their soul
to their companies. Jody Greenstone Miller, the founder of Business
Talent Group, says that her company’s comparative advantage lies in
rethinking corporate time: by breaking up work into projects, she can
allow people to work for as long as they want.
A limited Utopia
The on-demand economy is good for outsiders and insurgents—and for
entrepreneurs trying to create new businesses using such people. Matt
Barrie, the founder of Freelance.com, links the fate of two groups of
potential winners: entrepreneurs in the rich world who have few
resources will be able to link up with workers in the poor world who
have little money. In Europe the labour market drives a wedge between
insiders who have lots of protections and outsiders who don’t; on-demand
arrangements may give outsiders a chance of breaking in. Thus in
countries such as France, Italy and Spain, on-demand companies may
improve the job chances of the young unemployed.
If this seems attractive, it is also a measure of the way that the
on-demand economy will contribute to pressure to reduce labour rights in
all sorts of situations; a growing abundance of on-demand employees
with no normally accepted rights such as sick-pay and overtime will give
employers at firms with more standard structures an incentive to cut
back. The more such pressures spread, the more protests against
“Plattform-Kapitalismus” the world is likely to see.
The on-demand economy will inevitably exacerbate the trend towards
enforced self-reliance that has been gathering pace since the 1970s.
Workers who want to progress will have to keep their formal skills up to
date, rather than relying on the firm to train them (or to push them up
the ladder regardless). This means accepting challenging assignments
or, if they are locked in a more routine job, taking responsibility for
educating themselves. They will also have to learn how to drum up new
business and make decisions between spending and investment.
At the same time, governments will have to rethink institutions that
were designed in an era when contract employers were a rarity. They will
have to clean up complicated regulatory systems. They will have to make
it easier for individuals to take charge of their pensions and health
care, a change which will be more of a problem for America, which ties
many benefits to jobs, than Europe, which has a more universal approach.
They will also have to encourage schools to produce self-reliant
citizens rather than loyal employees.
One of Gilbert and Sullivan’s oddest operettas, “Utopia Limited—or
the Flowers of Progress”, focuses on an exotic South Sea island which,
under the influence of Victorian industrialism, sets about turning all
the inhabitants into limited companies. It is rarely performed today, in
part because the targets of its on-the-nose-in-1893 satire seem remote.
But perhaps, after a century in which companies were vast things, such a
satire of corporate individualism is due for a revival or two. If so,
the piece will be easier than ever to stage: if there are not already
on-demand services that can provide Polynesian props, semi-retired set
designers and down-on-their-luck tenors at the swipe of a screen, there
soon will be.